Conclusion

At the beginning, we considered an economics text sitting on the desk in front of you. Making sense of that text appeared to be a straightforward problem of reading carefully. By now, however, you may wonder what sense, or how many senses, you can make of the text! The problems that we have considered challenge any interpretation you may attempt, be it the construction of a general position along Stiglerian lines, a rational reconstruction, or a historical reconstruction. In conclusion, then, perhaps it is appropriate to summarize and emphasize the positive aspects of the issues we have considered.

First, as interpreters, we cannot escape the concerns of the times in which we live. We live in the present, and our historical interests are often animated by our present-day concerns. But the interpreter does have a choice as to whether she will interpret the text from the perspective of the present. Where the interpreter's interest is in bringing an historical author's work into dialogue with current economics, Stigler's principle of scientific exegesis is an appropriate guide. However, there is a thin line between rationally reconstructing the author's work in a way that enables the interpreter to identify its relation to modern thought and adopting the judgmental voice of Whig history. The latter should be avoided when the former is undertaken.

Secondly, whether the interpreter seeks to reconstruct the contemporary meaning of a text (rational reconstruction) or a historical meaning (historical reconstruction), less is more. The creation of a general statement of the author's position inevitably leads the interpreter to create a mythology; an abstraction from the author's work that will be upheld by appeal to some texts, but almost certainly falsified by others. Careful exegesis of specific texts, considering the range of meanings that they might have, the context in which they were created, and the purposes to which the author (or past interpreter) may have put them, will serve the interpreter well. Ironically, perhaps, abstract general positions turn out to be thinner representations of an author's work than either the contemporary rendering provided by a good rational reconstructions or the richly textured accounts that emerge from a good historical reconstruction.

Finally, the act of interpretation is a humbling experience. When we recognize the contingencies that shape the texts that we interpret, we also realize that our own ideas are limited by the context in which we live. And when the past speaks to us, we learn that others thought well - sometimes even better than we do.

Note

The author wishes to thank Bruce Janz and Anthony Waterman for conversations that enriched the views expressed here.

Bibliography

Bevir, M. 1999: The Logic of the History of Ideas. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

Blaug, M. 1985: Economic Theory in Retrospect. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

- 1990: On the historiography of economics. Journal of the History of Economic Thought,

Butterfield, H. 1931: The Whig Interpretation of History. London: Pelican. Derrida, J. 1976: Of Grammatology. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. Dilthey, W. 1976: Selected Writings. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Emmett, R. B. 1997: Reflections on "breaking away": economics as science and the history of economics as history of science. Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology, 15, 221-36.

Fish, S. 1980: Is There a Text in This Class? The Authority of Interpretive Communities. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Foucault, M. 1972: The Archaeology of Knowledge. London: Tavistock. Gadamer, H.-G. 1989: Truth and Method, 2nd revised edn. New York: Crossroad. Geertz, C. 1973: The Interpretation of Culture: Selected Essays. New York: Basic Books. Gerrard, B. 1993: The significance of interpretation in economics. In W. Henderson, T. Dudley-Evans, and R. Backhouse (eds.), Economics and Language. London: Routledge, 51-63.

Hahn, F. 1993: Autobiographical notes with reflections. In M. Szenberg (ed.), Eminent

Economists. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Heidegger, M. 1962: Being and Time, revised edition. New York: Harper & Row. Henderson, J. 1996: Whig history of economics is dead - Now what? http://www.eh.net/

HE/hes_list/Editorials/henderson.php Hollander, S. 1979: The Economics of David Ricardo. Toronto: University of Toronto Press. Hynes, A. 2001: Economics' past and present: historical analysis and current practice.

Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 23, 181-95. Kloppenberg, J. 1986: Uncertain Victory: Social Democracy and Progressivism in European and

American Social Thought 1870-1920. New York: Oxford University Press. Knight, F. H. 1921: Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit. Boston: Houghton Mifflin.

- 2000: The Ricardian theory of production and distribution. In R. B. Emmett (ed.),

Selected Essays by Frank H. Knight, vol. 1: "What is Truth" in Economics? Chicago: The

University of Chicago Press, 237-89. Originally published in the Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science, 1 (February and May 1935), 3-25 and 171-96.

Lavoie, D. (ed.) 1991: Economics and Hermeneutics. London: Routledge.

Levy, D. M. 2001: How the Dismal Science Got Its Name: Classical Economics & the Ur-Text of Racial Politics. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.

McCloskey, D. N. 1998: The Rhetoric of Economics. Madison, WI: University of Wisconsin Press.

Michelfelder, D. P. and Palmer, R. E. (eds.) 1989: Dialogue and Deconstruction: The Gadamer-Derrida Encounter. Albany, NY: State University of New York Press.

Patinkin, D. 1982: Anticipations of The General Theory? Oxford: Blackwell.

Pocock, J. G. A. 1962: The history of political thought: a methodological enquiry. In P. Laslett and W. Runciman (eds.), Philosophy, Politics and Society, second series. Oxford: Blackwell, 183-202.

- 1985: State of the art. In Virtue, Commerce and History. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge

University Press, 1-34.

Ricoeur, P. 1970: Freud and Philosophy: An Essay on Interpretation. New Haven, CN: Yale University Press.

-1981: Hermeneutics and the Human Sciences. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University

Press.

Roncaglia, A. 1996: Why should economists study the history of economic thought? The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 3, 296-309.

Rorty, R. 1984: The historiography of philosophy: four genres. In R. Rorty, J. B. Schneewind, and Q. Skinner (eds.), Philosophy in History: Essays on the Historiography of Philosophy. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 49-75.

Rutherford, M. 1994: Institutions in Economics: The Old and the New Institutionalism. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

Samuelson, P. 1987: Out of the closet: a program for the Whig history of science. History of Economics Society Bulletin, 9 (Fall), 51-60.

Skinner, Q. 1988: Meaning and understanding in the history of ideas. In J. Tully (ed.), Meaning and Context: Quentin Skinner and His Critics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 29-67. Originally published in History and Theory, 8 (1969), 3-53.

Sraffa, P. 1951: Introduction. In The Works and Correspondence of David Ricardo. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, for the Royal Economic Society.

Stigler, G. J. 1965: Textual exegesis as a scientific problem. Economica, 32, 447-50.

-1982: The scientific uses of scientific biography, with special reference to J. S. Mill. In

The Economist as Preacher and Other Essays. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. Originally published in Robson, J. M. and Laine, M. (eds.) 1976: James and John Stuart Mill: Papers of the Centenary Conference, Toronto: Toronto University Press.

Tully, J. (ed.) 1988: Meaning and Context: Quentin Skinner and His Critics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Waterman, A. M. C. 1988: Malthus on long swings: a reply. Canadian Journal of Economics, 21, 206-7.

Weintraub, R. 1991: Stabilizing Dynamics: Constructing Economic Knowledge. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

Weintraub, R., Meardon, S. J., Gayer, T., and Banzhaf, H. S. 1998: Archiving the history of economics. Journal of Economic Literature, 36, 1496-501.

Winch. D. 1996: Riches and Poverty: An Intellectual History of Political Economy in Britain, 1750-1834. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

- 2000: Does progress matter? The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought,

CHAPTER THIRTY-TWO

Was this article helpful?

0 0

Post a comment